When people talk about elections like horse races, policy doesn't matter—all we care about is who's likely to win. In this fetid theory of elections, governments tend to represent a kind of dissatisfying average of voter opinion. Everyone gets a little bit of the stuff they want, and everyone gets a large dose of the stuff they don't want.
Given this model, is it possible for voter opinion to become, essentially, decoupled from election outcomes? Something like this might be the case, according to an overly general model produced by—you guessed it—physicists.
Elections are unfriendly things to model. Put yourself in the position of the party apparatchik. In an ideal world, you would come up with policy that you think would improve the nation and then present that to the electorate. That is a losing strategy. Instead, policies and candidates are selected based on the opinion of the electorate, which doesn't always know what will improve the nation. That creates a tightly coupled dynamic: the candidates offered are based on the opinion of the electorate, and they, in turn, influence the opinion of the electorate.
This latest research suggests that, even without the complication of getting messy with reality, election models can produce some alarming dynamics.
The spherical-cow election
Imagine that everyone could summarize their political opinions using a single number. Now, in a rational world, everyone would vote for the candidate whose opinion is closest to your own, meaning their opinion number is closest to your own. In this case, election results are stable. That doesn't mean that each election result is the same but that the public selects a group of politicians that more or less matches the opinions of the majority of the electorate.
This is a stable election system, where a change of opinion in the electorate will be reflected by a change in the election result that is about the same size (or maybe a bit smaller).
However, we are not rational. Sometimes, the nearest candidate is still too far away from your own opinion. In this case, you might not be bothered to vote. Not voting because of the lack of close representation, it turns out, has deeper consequences than imagined.
The researchers define something called negative representation. In the case of negative representation, the opinion of the electorate—or part of the electorate—might shift in one direction, but the election results will go in the opposite direction. This is what can happen when voters refuse to vote.
Even worse, the presence of negative representation can result in instability. That is, the change in an election result is larger than the change in the opinions of the electorate. What's more, it doesn't matter if the non-voters are clumped at one end of the spectrum or evenly distributed—the effect is the same.
Show me the wild elections
We know that there are elements of this in most electoral systems, where a substantial fraction of voters abstain because they feel that no candidate represents them well enough.Read More – Source
[contf] [contfnew]
arstechnica
[contfnewc] [contfnewc]